Make It Forty-Four Shades of Green

BrianCzechLast month in “Forty Shades of… Less Brown?,” I described the principle of increasing marginal brownness. This principle establishes that the process of economic growth invariably entails an environmental “browning,” even though some growth regimes are less brown than others. The idea is to use the brown portion of the color spectrum in framing discussions of economic growth. Otherwise it is too easy to fall for the seductive and dangerous rhetoric of “green growth.”

Don’t let the title of this week’s column fool you. I haven’t been drinking the Green Kool-Aid. This week we’re using the green portion of the spectrum, alright, but in a surprisingly different context.

You may recall that I concluded last month’s column with a stunning observation from the Eastern Economic Association conference in Philadelphia. Despite the stereotype we have of economists as wild-eyed growth-at-all-costers, pumping their fists for perpetually increasing GDP, something new was afoot in Philly. In fact, the overwhelming majority of economists I spoke with agreed wholeheartedly that there is a fundamental conflict between economic growth and environmental protection. They acknowledged limits to growth and even concurred that wealthy nations, at least, should adopt the goal of a steady state economy!

“Proove it,” you said? I offered to do just that.

Proving it is easy, thanks to the CASSE position on economic growth. The CASSE position states precisely that there is “a fundamental conflict between economic growth and environmental protection.” It also states that a steady state economy “has become a more appropriate goal in large, wealthy economies.” Forty-four conferees signed the CASSE position right there in Philadelphia. So there’s your proof!

Only a few conferees that I spoke with declined to sign the CASSE position, at least for the time being. Even these few may lend their good names at some point. None were openly opposed to it, either, and it is not uncommon for a prominent scholar (the type I sought) or public figure to ponder the significance of a statement for some time prior to signing it. But for EEA leaders past and present (such as Ingrid Rima and Steven Pressman, respectively), the CASSE position contained little to even hesitate about.

So what’s going on here? What happened to our stereotype of the professional economist as denying limits to growth, based on simplistic notions of perpetual technological progress? After all, that stereotype is not without a basis in fact. Examples abound, and one of my personal favorites (in a sense) was the wackiness of one Robert Bradley: “Natural resources originate from the mind, not the ground, and therefore are not depletable.” This, while receiving the Julian Simon Award from the Cato Institute! (Simon is another story altogether, which I covered in Chapter 4 of Shoveling Fuel for a Runaway Train). The stereotype was not only well-deserved but proudly flaunted during decades of neoclassical nuttiness.

Therein lies a key word: “neoclassical.” This is the brand of economics most responsible for our stereotype. Neoclassical economics is exemplified and promulgated by the Chicago School, and it’s increasingly credited with a variety of crisis-causing shortcomings. A short list of neoclassical icons would include Frank Knight, Milton Friedman, and Alan Greenspan. Let it be quickly said that these are (or were) no dummies, but neither should they have been expected to know everything, or even something, about ecological affairs and long-run economic sustainability. And these are (or were) the cream of the neoclassical crop.

As a matter of lingo, at least in the U.S., the neoclassical brethren have recently been labeled “freshwater” economists by themselves and by journalists, indicating the prominence of Chicago and some other inland schools as bastions of neoclassical thought. This is probably a welcome development for many neoclassicals who would gladly trade the stigma of “neoclassical” for the cleanly sound of “freshwater.”

Our stereotype of the GDP Growthman, then, should have always been attributed primarily to neoclassical economists, not economists at large. The problem for sustainability is that the neoclassicals comprise a large and influential portion of economists, especially those appointed to government posts and those running the Federal Reserve System. That shouldn’t be a surprise, when you think about the influence of Big Money in government and academia. The historical linkage of Big Money and neoclassical economics is described in Mason Gaffney’s Corruption of Economics, among others.

But our focus is these other, non-neoclassical economists, so prominent at the EEA conference. Who are they? To start with, there are the Keynesians, neo-Ricardians, Austrians, Sraffians, Marxists, and Georgists (some of my personal favorites). There are also the “saltwater” economists who tend to synthesize neoclassical and Keynesian thought. There are numerous subdivisions among these broad categories, too, such as “red” Marxists, “green” Marxists, and even Marxists who conclude, like Marx did, that “I am no Marxist.” The point is that many, and perhaps a large majority, of these economists would reject the neoclassical notion of unlimited growth, if given the chance.

Of course, we also have ecological economics, for which limits to growth is the starting point and top priority for analysis and policy reform. The fact that there is a limit to economic growth is not an “assumption” in ecological economics, but a scientifically sound and nuanced conclusion, and other topics in ecological economics must square therewith. I hesitate to list ecological economics among these other schools of thought, though. Ecological economics doesn’t yet have the historical cachet or the strength in numbers, certainly not of the Keynesians, Marxists, or neoclassicals. Nor does it have a strong presence in the policy arena, yet.

Perhaps more importantly, unlike these other traditions in economics, ecological economics is as much ecology as economics. It is sometimes described as a “transdiscipline,” transcending even an “interdisciplinary” approach of combining environmental and economic concerns. Ecological economics is not just about applying another twist from the social sciences to economic affairs. Rather, it is about basing the social science of economics on a solid foundation of natural sciences, especially physics and ecology. At this point in history, with a crowded planet replete with climate change and a burgeoning list of endangered species, falling over like canaries in the coalmine, ecological economics should become a presence in conventional economic affairs.

That brings us back to the EEA. Unlike the American Economic Association, historically dominated by neoclassical economists, the EEA is known for its openness to the various schools of thought. Economists of all ilks, including neoclassicals but not excluding the others, assemble at the annual conference. In Philadelphia, for example, Gregory Mankiw gave the presidential address, marking his exit as the figurehead of the EEA and making way for the presidency of Duncan Foley.

Foley is a free-ranging, highly respected economics professor with a remarkably diverse approach that defies categorization. Meanwhile, Mankiw is squarely in the neoclassical hall of fame. A leading author of neoclassical textbooks, Mankiw served as the Chairman of the President’s Council of Economic Advisors under George W. Bush. Yet, when I talked with him about the CASSE position on economic growth, even he seemed curious and willing to consider the merits. This may reflect the saltwater in his intellectual veins. It might reflect a healthy dose of common sense, too. Perhaps this neoclassical icon will be a CASSE signatory at some point.

Although the neoclassical stereotype has a basis in fact, some benefit of the doubt should be allocated to the neoclassical forebears. After all, the Knights, Friedmans, and Greenspans of the neoclassical world cut their macroeconomic teeth in an age dramatically different from ours. Even conservation heroes such as Rachel Carson and Aldo Leopold, mid-century contemporaries with the neoclassical icons, weren’t talking clearly about limits to economic growth. You can almost read about it between the lines (especially the last lines of Leopold), but explicitly describing the conflict between economic growth and environmental protection is only a recent development, even among the ecological professions. Furthermore, it’s slow going there, too. One organization, the Ecological Society of America, is still sipping the “sustainable growth” Kool-Aid (sickening a considerable share of members in the oxymoronic process).

The point is that neoclassical economists should not get all the blame for promulgating economic growth beyond the optimum, also known as “uneconomic growth.” The fact is, many of them may be undertaking a paradigm shift and may soon shed the stereotype they inherited. Mankiw, for example, didn’t get where he is by being oblivious to world affairs or unable to adapt. If a scholar and leader of his ability had received his education in the ecological sciences along with economics, he conceivably could have been a steady state economist on par with Herman Daly. The CASSE blog might be called The Daly News and Mankiw Views. Furthermore, to the extent that Mankiw and other prominent figures in neoclassical economics are noting the world around them, and are “shocked” (as Greenspan allowed) in retrospect by the shortcomings of neoclassical economics, it isn’t too late for them to part with their perpetual-growth past.

While talking with Mankiw in Philadelphia, I noted the stark contrast with the conversation I’d had with Robert Lucas (the Chicago School growth theorist) after his presidential address, for the American Economic Association. I asked Lucas if he thought there was a limit to economic growth, and he automatically replied, “No, that’s what technological progress is for.” It was as if I had tapped his knee with a rubber hammer, and his perpetual-growth kick was instantaneous. This may not be entirely a matter of his freshwater, neoclassical lineage, though. It’s been 8 years since I questioned Lucas, and a lot of economic and ecological crises have probably shaken the faith of neoclassicals in the intervening years. Certainly a lot of faith in the neoclassical school has been shaken, which presumably would engender some re-inspection of neoclassical theory.

If Lucas is impervious to critique, or too stubborn to re-inspect his neoclassical paradigm, and fails to apply his renowned calculus to growth limits, he will forfeit what could otherwise be a grand finale of applied and important mathematics. Instead, he will be a last bastion of an unsustainable, stereotypical, 20th century neoclassical mistake. Other economists that have thought their way through the perpetual-growth nonsense, identifying the key ecological principles with due diligence, will take his place in the annals of economic thought.

That brings us back to the EEA conference and the conclusion of this week’s Daly News. The professional economists, professors, and students populating the EEA were fun, smart, and even inspirational to be with. In turn, many of them were inspired by the CASSE mission, with forty-four of them signing the CASSE position on economic growth. That included Georgists, Keynesians, Marxists… even some neoclassicals of a “kinder, gentler” sort for the 21st century. So it is a pleasure, a fond memory, indeed an honor, to conclude by celebrating the fine, forward-thinking members of the EEA. Although the right color to use in economic growth discussions is brown, a good way to describe the EEA economists is with forty shades – actually, make that forty-four shades – of green!

Print Friendly, PDF & Email
9 replies
  1. Eriall Steiner
    Eriall Steiner says:

    Awesomeness! But maybe instead of disclaimer stickers on his textbooks, Mankiw will be inspired to help author some more enlightened texts and spare future econ students the struggle (I’ve been through) of trying to make/find more solid congruency between the theories studied in class and the laws of nature & physics. I know I’d appreciate that!
    Keep up the good work!

    Reply
  2. wendy
    wendy says:

    Wonderful ; I wish you would come over to the UK and dispense some much-needed wisdom to our oxymoronic politicians in the run-up to our General Election.

    They are vying with one another to offer: sustainable growth; tax cuts; environmental protection; social justice; reduction in national deficit; action on climate change………

    The voters are not impressed.

    Reply
  3. Joshua Nelson
    Joshua Nelson says:

    Brian,

    I feel the momentum building on this issue and it is wonderful to hear news of more economists of all types signing the CASSE position. I hope we’ll hear more from Mankiw in the future, as well as his colleagues. The mere fact that the issues of ecological sustainability are permeating the economic thinkers is a huge step for everyone concerned about the conflict of economic growth and the environment.

    Cheers,
    Joshua

    Reply
  4. Wayne Tyson
    Wayne Tyson says:

    Brian:

    As usual, I (almost) agree with you. That dispensed with, let’s get to where we diverge. No, let’s talk about where we agree. (I’m a wishy-washy guy.)

    We agree on the fundamentals—growth can’t go up and up forever.

    I know this was a kind of report on the EEA meeting, but I’m from and in the West (that’s another issue). Worse, I’m not in the economists, or, for that matter, the ecologists, social swim. That’s neither bad nor good, it just is. But it does affect my credibility. While I may feel passionately about the subject, I’m not nuts about reading even your clearly brilliant prose when I have to fish the substance out from between the lines. It’s a time thing!

    Those of us out here on the fringes want most to be able to dip into your pool and come out refreshed—updated on progress with respect to the substance of the issue. There was some of this imbedded in your rhetoric (and I won’t say that it doesn’t bear repeating), but I still don’t know in what specific respect “things” have changed in the last half-decade or so, heartwarming as it is to hear that more and more economists have started to waver from the “whatever-classical” line of economic “thinking.” I want to be able to start, when I take a dip in your pool at the cutting edge and work myself back to familiar territory—and beyond—to refresh my memory. I also want to get to a summary and fish backwards from there into deeper and deeper intellectual water on the subject.

    You work hard at this, and for that I am eternally grateful. I wish, however, that you could get a wider, serious enough readership than four comments would seem to imply.
    I’m glad to hear that you get it that terms like “sustainable” and “green” are buzzwords, but are you serious about adding “brown?” Is this another sniff at the West? Ok, that’s another issue. But seriously, folks, there’s a lot to be learned from the literal and figurative West, out where ecotones are sharp as cactus spines, brown though it may be.

    Even though I got an “A” on my 1965 paper for discussing proto-economics, I could not progress in my insistence that it is no accident that economics and ecology are more than etymologically related (as I did before a banquetroomful of ecologists in 1987 to barely polite applause and no comments). I am heartened that you have been vastly more successful. I want you to be more so. So, keep slugging, and keep trying to find ways to avoid the buzzwords.

    Finally, permit me to emphasize the point that perpetual growth is a snare and a delusion within the bounds of so-called “economics,” completely apart from ecology (though it isn’t). If history late and early is not enough, if the “neo’s” don’t get it that no matter how big the bubbles are, they eventually go bust, I don’t know how the ecological metaphor, green, brown, or otherwise, will swing them around.

    Yr. Ob’t. Sv’t.
    Wayne Tyson

    Reply
  5. Wayne Tyson
    Wayne Tyson says:

    Re: “Forty Shades of… Less Brown?”

    I’m posting here because posting is apparently closed for comment on the March 7 post–I hope that doesn’t violate a rule or custom (perhaps that’s why the number of comments appears to be smaller than it should be?). However, they are related, so . . .

    Brian:

    I’m kinda working backwards; I started with your subsequent April 4, 2010 post, then read this one, gaining, I hope, a somewhat better understanding.

    At root, organisms tend to consume their resource-base until it restricts their growth—or causes a bust (radical, relatively sudden restriction or extinction) right? Or wrong? If it is true that “we” are wiser than the other, presumably dumber animals (an unproven hypothesis), it would seem to follow that we should be capable of predicting the consequences of our own actions, no? If consumption increases exponentially or even geometrically, it would seem, would it not, that the prediction would be along the lines of high-living, full-of-abandon, wasteful, trinket-obsessed, beyond-hedonism? Now, if SOME of us, reduce our consumption, we will get our just reward, right? The rest will get their reward for OUR conservation of resources—greater high-living, full-of-abandon, wasteful, trinket-obsessed, BEYOND-beyond-hedonism, no? The ULTIMATE CRASH will perhaps be altered, perhaps not, in its rough proportion to the gross (unsustainable) over-consumption regardless of the conservation:waste ratio, will it not?

    So—will a trend toward altering the ratio may buy time (if it turns out there is enough time) to change the ratio further, and reduce the demand placed on the resource-base to the point where it can recover until there is surplus enough to sustain “normal” fluctuations around that ratio—a steady-state or equilibrium in which we may teeter and totter about the tipping point but not fall fall so hard we can’t get up? That is, we should be able to ease ourselves into a state beyond total misery and total luxury that existed, say, in pre-contact Polynesia somewhere, but was not envied by the self-righteous invaders of the “advanced” cultures?

    What am I missing here?

    Wayne Tyson

    PS: I’m new to your site; once I get the hang of it, maybe I’ll shape up. (I saw too late that I left out some possessive apostrophes; hope I haven’t offended any sticklers . . .)

    Reply
  6. RK Bangert
    RK Bangert says:

    It still amazes me that economists are starting to change their thinking, but the Ecological Society of America seems unable to progress in their thinking. This is a serious let down for ecologists.

    toodles – randy

    Reply
  7. thompsco
    thompsco says:

    Well, I guess my respect for Mankiw just went up a notch. I remember reading some of his statements about population and growth a few years ago and wrote him off as a hopeless case. But, if he was “curious” about a steady state economy, that’s huge progress.

    Sounds like Mr. Lucas may have farther to go. But I’ll hold good thoughts that more will come around.

    Reply

Leave a Reply

Want to join the discussion?
Feel free to contribute!
(No profanity, lewdness, or libel.)

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *